The
purpose of any economic exchange is to better one's position, whether
a person buys or sells something for money or barters for something
else. This is the essence of free market capitalism, where all
economic transactions are voluntary because they are of
mutual benefit. They are all “win-win”
situations in the minds of the participants.
By contrast,
when a government compels an economic transaction, it is always
“win-lose” because one side gains when a loss is inflicted on the
other, as evidenced by the fact it wouldn't voluntarily agree to it.
This is the essence of a planned economy, where an elite in
government is believed better able to decide what is best for
everybody than allowing people to determine that for themselves. It
is assumed that some losses are inevitable—and are usually blamed
on capitalism—and that government must ameliorate this by managing
(distributing) the losses, and benefits, for the greater overall
benefit of society. This may include benefiting the environment.
The idea that
an aggregation of win-lose transactions can somehow produce an
economy superior to one of win-win transactions is ludicrous. It is
all the more so when one realizes that initial losses produce
secondary ones in the same way that benefits of free markets produce
secondary benefits for society. And this includes benefiting the
environment.
Take ethanol,
for example. Initially it was supported because it was widely
claimed the world was running out of oil—now shown to be untrue
because technology has proven there will be no shortage for thousands
of years, if ever. So now it is being argued that ethanol is
important because it reduces air pollution and global warming and
promotes jobs in the ethanol industry. It is even said to be
competitive with gasoline.
Farmers raising
corn and manufacturers producing ethanol benefit from federal and
state subsidies. The losers are the taxpayers, who pay not only
through direct taxes for the subsidies but through higher costs for
fuel and electricity (due not only to ethanol but to the government's
effort to eliminate coal in the production of electricity.) As a
result, people have correspondingly less money to spend on other
things. Those would-be benefits are foregone, lost without being
seen. The beneficiaries of ethanol (and wind and solar) subsidies
spend their subsidy money, but much of it goes for farm machinery and
labor to raise more corn for ethanol and build more solar panels and
wind farms, rather than things that are more useful in society. Thus
losses of mandated energy inefficiency beget secondary losses in
inefficient industries, just as the efficiencies of free markets
beget secondary benefits in more useful and efficient industries that
would come about if the money for them were not preempted by the
requirement for inefficient fuels.
Another class
of losers from ethanol is the consumers of corn as food, primarily
poor people in Latin American countries. The use of corn in ethanol
tripled in three years, and the World Bank report noted that
biofuels
forced global food prices up by 75% — far more than previously
estimated.
More U.S. corn now goes for ethanol than is consumed as food. The
World Food Program, the United Nations' Food and Agriculture
Organization, and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development have formally called for all G20 nations to drop their
biofuels subsidies and mandates because of the adverse impact on food
prices around the world.
How inefficient
is ethanol? First we must recognize two unbreakable laws of the
universe. The first law of thermodynamics (conservation) states that
energy is neither created nor destroyed, but only changes form. The
second law (entropy) distinguishes between useful energy that can
perform work and useless energy that cannot, and “some
fraction of useful energy irreversibly becomes useless every time
energy is converted from one form to another,” explains
T.A. Kiefer. “Together, these two laws declare
that the amount of useful energy that can be recovered from a system
is always less than the energy that was put into the system. Every
transaction, process, or conversion pays an energy tax, which is why
it is impossible to construct a perpetual motion machine. The ratio
of energy-out to energy-in is a critical parameter in evaluating
energy sources.”
A key
measure, then, is the energy return on investment (EROI),
a ratio of energy from a new fuel to the energy consumed in
producing it. An EROI of 1:1 would
mean that the useful energy produced by the new fuel would exactly
equal the energy needed to produce it. Kiefer writes:
“A
civilization is itself a high-order physical and biological
organism that has tremendous overhead costs and can spare only a
fraction of its energy to assimilate new energy. A study of
historical US economic performance over the last century has found
that economic recessions are linked to primary energy EROIs dipping
below a critical threshold of 6:1. This value represents the minimum
energy quality an industrial civilization must have to sustain a
modern, energy-intensive quality of life. Another macroanalysis found
that an EROI of 3:1 is the bare minimum quality a raw energy feed-stock
must have to overcome all the production costs and conversion losses
and still deliver positive net energy to modern civilization. A 3:1
EROI thus also represents a critical tipping point. To put these
values in biological terms, a modern industrial civilization is very
energy-hungry, and if undernourished on a diet of foods with lean
EROIs below 6:1, it becomes catabolic, eating into the fat of its
savings and the muscle tissue of its infrastructure to replace the
missing calories. As long as EROI remains below 6:1, industrial
civilization is locked into a death spiral where an ever increasing
fraction of its economic output (GDP) is spent on energy at the cost
of eroding standard of living. At EROIs below 3:1, the food is so
poor that digesting it into fuel takes more energy than it returns,
and full starvation sets in. The only way out of this hunger trap is
either to find higher-EROI energy or to decay into a preindustrial
civilization with lower energy needs. The bottom line is that a
healthy modern economy must be fed by hearty primary energy sources
with a collective EROI above 6:1. [Incidentally, the EROI for coal is 30:1]
“After
decades of study and experimentation and continuously refined
commercial production, the scientific literature consensus for corn
ethanol EROI is a lowly value of 1.25:1. Even worse, there is no net
gain in liquid fuel energy—the ethanol produced contains energy
barely equal to the input fossil fuel energy. The small energy profit
is contained in byproducts, principally high-protein biorefinery
leftovers called distillers’ dry grains and solubles (DDGS) that
can be used as cattle feed. More than $6 billion a year in direct
federal assistance to corn growers and ethanol refiners since 2005
has served only to reduce a nonexistent foreign dependence on animal
feed protein supplements. It should be pointed out that the corn
ethanol EROIs published in the literature and discussed above are not
for a pure corn ethanol life-cycle, but for a hybrid lifecycle
involving both fossil fuel and corn ethanol where fossil fuel
provides much of the input energy. A proper corn ethanol EROI would
be calculated using corn ethanol as the exclusive energy source to
make more corn ethanol, but no example is available today. This is
telling. It will be shown...by lifecycle analysis that making corn
ethanol is a negative energy-balance process that consumes more than
five-sixths of the energy invested. Civilization would get six times
more output energy from the fossil fuel diverted to make corn ethanol
if it were instead used directly as fuel.”
Ammonia,
which is made from natural gas, is second only to plastic in
consumption of industrial energy in the U.S., and 80 percent of
ammonia is used in making fertilizer. Use of fertilizer is the main
reason for the six-fold increase in corn production in recent
decades, without which ethanol would be more easily recognized as
uneconomic. Kiefer writes,
“Modern intensively farmed corn, with its huge appetite for fossil
fuel-based ammonia and agrichemicals, is making a large, net negative
contribution
to the nation’s energy budget ….Biofuels can never be cheaper
than nor replace fossil fuels while fossil fuels comprise the bulk of
the energy invested to make them....Applying ammonia fertilizer to
any crop intended for biofuel is an indefensible waste of energy.”
Hosein
Shapouri, an employee of the U.S. Department of Agriculture, has
produced a study of ethanol showing a small net benefit from ethanol.
But Howard Hayden, a Professor Emeritus of Physics from the
University of Connecticut and Adjunct Professor at the University of
Southern Colorado, notes that Shapouri et al “use the most
optimistic figures: the best corn yield, the least energy
used for fertilizer, the least energy required for farming,
the most efficient distillation techniques, the most
residual energy (in the form of mash); and in general the most
favorable (but still credible) values for any and all aspects of
[ethanol] production.” Even so, Hayden says that, using Shapouri's
numbers, the net average power available from the ethanol of one acre
of corn would be enough only to keep one 60-watt light bulb burning
continuously for one month. To keep that bulb burning for a
year would require 12 acres of corn—an area larger than nine
football fields.
Puny
though that energy gain from ethanol would be, even that is
controversial. A thorough study done by Cornell University
Professor David Pimmentel, who also chaired a U.S. Department of
Energy panel to investigate the energetics of ethanol production,
found Shapouri had left out many energy inputs. These include farm
labor, farm machinery, repair of farm machinery, energy to produce
the hybrid corn, and irrigation. Pimmentel also says Shapouri gives
an extravagant credit for distillers dry grains (DDGS), which are
used for animal feed as a substitute for soybean meal. Pimmentel
says, “We
went back to the soybean meal, and examined how it’s produced, and
the energy that is required to produce it. Instead of giving
[distillers grains] a 40 to 60 percent credit as the pro-ethanol
people do, we found that the credit should be more like 9 percent.
They [pro-ethanol researchers] are manipulating the data again.”
Incidentally, soybean meal has 49 percent protein content compared to
27 percent for DDGS.
Cellulosic
ethanol, produced from wood, switch grass, and harvest wastes is even
more uneconomic than corn ethanol. Cellulose can be broken into
fermentable sugars using concentrated acid and explosive steam, but
this one step consumes as much energy as exists in the final ethanol.
Thermodynamic analysis shows cellulosic ethanol is at least three
times more difficult to produce than corn ethanol and has an EROI far
below 1:1.
Biodiesel
and other liquid biofuels have shortcomings that require
“hydrotreating” to change the hydrogen-carbon ratio, remove all
oxygen, and change the molecular structure to make them compatible
with high performance engines and existing fuel infrastructure.
Hydrotreatment greatly increases the cost and releases 11 tons of
carbon dioxide for every ton of hydrogen added.
Algae
is even worse. According to the Argonne
National Laboratory, it takes 12 times as much energy and 2.6
times as much fossil fuel energy to put a gallon of algae diesel in a
gas station pump as a gallon of petroleum diesel—and that's without
counting hydrotreatment.
Kiefer's
research is based
on “an extensive literature survey of recent
and reputable sources emphasizing U.S. government agency data
published in official reports and university studies published in
peer-reviewed scientific journals. Since 2008, a new generation of
more rigorous studies has dramatically
undermined the naïve assumption that biofuels are inherently clean
and green.”
He
writes:
“Compared to the petroleum fuel
lifecycle, the corn ethanol fuel lifecycle consumes 3.5 times more
fossil fuel, more than triples Greenhouse Gas emissions, increases
water use by three orders of magnitude, adds environmental costs from
agrichemical runoff while still suffering those associated with crude
oil, and competes with food cultivation for cropland acreage and
associated agricultural production capital and resources.”
Finally,
Kiefer provides here
an extensive list of studies for his assertion, “New,
more thorough studies that consider the full fuel creation and
combustion lifecycles are now showing cultivated liquid
biofuels to be more damaging to the environment and causing the
release of more CO2 and
other greenhouse gases and pollutants per unit of energy delivered
than fossil fuels.”
No comments:
Post a Comment